Skip to Content

Fat tax

« Back to Glossary Index

**Purpose and Benefits of Fat Tax**:
– Public health practitioners advocate for a fat tax to discourage unhealthy diets.
– Research shows a link between the obesity epidemic and the expansion of the fast food industry.
– The aim of a fat tax is to shift consumer preferences towards healthier food choices.
– Implementing a fat tax is expected to lead to improved health outcomes by reducing obesity-related diseases.
– Taxing tobacco has successfully reduced smoking rates, prompting calls for fat taxes to combat unhealthy food consumption.

**Criticism and Challenges of Fat Tax**:
– Lower-income households may struggle with a fat tax as cheaper unhealthy foods are their main source of nutrition.
– There is a risk of inadvertently taxing healthy foods high in fats, like nuts and avocados.
– Previous experiences with similar taxes on tobacco and alcohol show mixed success in changing consumer behavior.
– Poorer households, spending a significant portion of income on food, may find it difficult to afford healthier options if taxed.
– Instances like the sugary drinks tax in Philadelphia have seen consumers circumvent the tax rather than switching to healthier options.

**History and Evolution of Fat Tax**:
– The first fat taxes were introduced in the USA in 1925, focusing on food purity rather than fattening properties.
– Notable figures like Kelly Brownell advocated for fat taxes to address the imbalance in food costs.
– The World Health Organization proposed junk food taxes in 2003 to encourage healthier food choices globally.
– The concept gained traction in the late 1970s and early 1980s, with proposals to use tax revenue to subsidize healthier foods and nutrition campaigns.
– In 1942, a physiologist suggested a fee on overweight individuals to promote food availability during wartime.

**Implementation and Effectiveness of Fat Tax**:
– A fat tax targets fattening foods, beverages, or overweight individuals to discourage unhealthy diets.
– Studies suggest that taxing sugar-sweetened beverages can significantly reduce consumption.
– Recommendations include earmarking tax revenues to subsidize healthy foods and health education to mitigate regressive impacts.
– Careful consideration is needed to avoid unintended consequences, like increased salt intake due to taxing saturated fats.
– A fat tax does not limit consumer choice but alters relative prices to encourage healthier food consumption.

**Global Perspectives on Fat Tax**:
Denmark introduced and later repealed the world’s first fat tax due to criticism.
– Japan and the UK have considered implementing fat taxes.
– Kerala, India imposed a 14.5% fat tax on junk food.
– Varied success and challenges have been observed in different countries regarding the implementation of fat taxes.
– Continued debate exists on the efficacy of fat taxes in combating obesity.

Fat tax (Wikipedia)

A fat tax is a tax or surcharge that is placed upon fattening food, beverages or on overweight individuals. It is considered an example of Pigovian taxation. A fat tax aims to discourage unhealthy diets and offset the economic costs of obesity.

A fat tax aims to decrease the consumption of foods that are linked to obesity. A related idea is to tax foods that are linked to increased risk of coronary heart disease. Numerous studies suggest that as the price of a food decreases, individuals get fatter. In fact, eating behavior may be more responsive to price increases than to nutritional education. Estimates suggest that a 1 cent per ounce tax on sugar-sweetened beverages may reduce the consumption of those beverages by 25%. However, there is also evidence that obese individuals are less responsive to changes in the price of food than normal-weight individuals.

To implement a fat tax, it is necessary to specify which food and beverage products will be targeted. This must be done with care, because a carelessly chosen food tax can have surprising and perverse effects. For instance, consumption patterns suggest that taxing saturated fat would induce consumers to increase their salt intake, thereby putting themselves at greater risk for cardiovascular death. Current proposals frequently single out sugar-sweetened drinks as a target for taxation. Cross-sectional, prospective, and experimental studies have found an association between obesity and the consumption of sugar-sweetened drinks. However, experimental studies have not always found an association, and the size of the effect can be very modest.

Since the poor spend a greater proportion of their income on food, a fat tax might be regressive. Taxing foods that provide primarily calories, with little other nutritional value reduces this problem, since calories are readily available from many sources in diet of industrialized nations. To make a fat tax less burdensome for the poor, proponents recommend earmarking the revenues to subsidize healthy foods and health education. Additionally, proponents have argued that the fat tax is less regressive to the extent that it lowers medical expenditures and expenditures on the targeted foods among the poor. Indeed, there is a higher incidence of diet-related illnesses among the poor than in the general population.[citation needed]

Unlike placing restrictions on foods or ingredients, a fat tax would not limit consumer choice, only change relative prices.

« Back to Glossary Index